Written by Thomas R. Eddlem, Friday, 18 January 2013
This year — 2013 — marks the 100th anniversary of the
modern income tax, a tax that dominates the revenue scheme of the federal
government today. Individual income taxes accounted for about 45 percent of all
federal tax revenue in 2012, along with 35 percent for Social Security and
Medicare payroll taxes (which are also a tax on income), 10 percent for
corporate income taxes, and only 10 percent for all other tax sources.
It wasn’t always so. Prior to ratification of the 16th
(income tax) Amendment in February 1913, the federal government managed its few
constitutional responsibilities without an income tax, except during the Civil
War period. During peacetime, it did so largely — or even entirely — on import
taxes called “tariffs.” Congress could afford to run the federal government on
tariffs alone because federal responsibilities did not include welfare
programs, agricultural subsidies, or social insurance programs like Social
Security or Medicare. After the Civil War, tariff revenues sometimes suffered
under a protectionist policy ushered in by the Republican Party that
supplemented federal income via excises on alcohol, tobacco, and inheritances.
But before the war, the need for tariff revenue to finance the federal
government generally kept the tariff at reasonable levels. During wartime
throughout early American history, the Founding Fathers were able to raise
additional revenue employing a different method of direct taxation authorized
by the U.S. Constitution prior to the 16th Amendment. These alternative taxing
methods gave the young American nation embarrassing peacetime budget surpluses
that several times came close to paying off the national debt.
In one instance, the U.S. government paid off its
entire national debt without the existence of an Internal Revenue Service.
President Andrew Jackson boasted in his veto of the Maysville Road Bill in 1830
that God had blessed the nation with no taxes (except tariffs on imports) and
no national debt:
Through the favor of an overruling and indulgent
Providence our country is blessed with a general prosperity and our citizens
exempted from the pressure of taxation, which other less favored portions of
the human family are obliged to bear.... How gratifying the effect of
presenting to the world the sublime spectacle of a Republic of more than
12,000,000 happy people, in the fifty-fourth year of her existence, after
having passed through two protracted wars — one for the acquisition and the
other for the maintenance of liberty — free from debt and all her immense
resources unfettered!
In reality, Jackson had jumped the gun on his boast.
The national debt would not be paid off for five more years, until the 1828
“Tariff of Abominations,” which were high tariffs primarily on British
manufactured goods meant to protect northern U.S. industries, and as the
compromise tariffs of 1832 and 1833 had created several years of massive budget
surpluses. But “Old Hickory” presided over a nation where Congress had
abolished all federal internal taxes, and no citizen saw a tax collector of the
United States unless that citizen was in the business of importing foreign
goods. And while American consumers were occasionally manipulated by
outrageously high protective tariffs, especially the above-mentioned “Tariff of
Abominations,” inside the United States a massive free market emerged over
which the U.S. government had almost no influence. Even the Tariff of
Abominations was not so high that it choked off revenue for imports from every
industry.
By way of contrast, the advent of the income tax
prompted some congressmen to note that this tax was designed not principally
for revenue — the U.S. government had always had plenty of money from tariffs —
but to manipulate the American people and their choices in the market. “The
character of the argument which had been made,” Massachusetts Rep. Samuel
McCall argued in a speech before the U.S. House of Representatives as Congress
debated the 16th Amendment, legalizing the income tax in 1909, “leads me to
believe that the chief purpose of the tax is not financial, but social. It is
not primarily to raise money for the state, but to regulate the citizen and to
regenerate the moral nature of man. The individual citizen will be called on to
lay bare the inner-most recesses of his soul in affidavits, and with the aid of
the Federal inspector, who will supervise his books and papers and business
secrets, he may be made to be good, according the notions of virtue at the
moment prevailing in Washington.” McCall’s Massachusetts constituents rewarded
the Republican congressman’s efforts by electing him governor several years
later.
This has been the legacy of the income tax. While the
income tax has produced the type of revenue that has made a massive transfer of
wealth from the productive to the unproductive possible, the incentives —
through thousands of deductions and tax credits — have manipulated the American
people into choices that they wouldn’t have otherwise made in a free market.
These manipulations — whether in favor of “green energy” research, “cash for
clunker” automobile purchases, or tobacco crop subsidies — have been chosen according
to the prevailing virtue in Washington.
The conservative Massachusetts congressman had been
more right in his position than even he could have guessed. And he serves as a
reminder that Massachusetts once produced leaders that promoted the idea of limited
government.
Massachusetts, in ratifying the 1787 Constitution,
recommended the following: “That Congress do not lay direct taxes but when the
moneys arising from the impost and excise are insufficient for the public
exigencies, nor then until Congress shall have first made a requisition upon
the States to assess, levy, and pay, their respective proportions of such
requisition, agreeably to the census fixed in the said Constitution, in such
way and manner as the legislatures of the States shall think best.” Statesmen
from Massachusetts sought to save their fellow citizens from the pestilence and
manipulation of federal tax collectors, and even suggested that this be part of
a constitutional amendment. Other founding-era leaders across the nation expressed
the same hope that the states would be given an opportunity to pay direct
federal taxes and avoid federal tax collectors, something that happened with
most direct taxes imposed before the Civil War.
Direct taxes are taxes imposed on people or property,
whereas indirect taxes are taxes on conditional events such as retail sales.
The U.S. Constitution granted Congress the power to impose direct or indirect
taxes, except a tax on exports, so long as the indirect taxes were “uniform”
and direct taxes were imposed within states in proportion to population. The
U.S. Constitution, Article I, Section 2 stipulates: “Representatives and direct
taxes shall be apportioned among the several states which may be included
within this union, according to their respective numbers.”
Paying Off the Revolutionary War Debt
The Founding Fathers sought to pay off the massive
debt from the War of Independence by imposing taxes on imports (tariffs) as
well as taxes on the sale of alcohol and tobacco (which are called “excises”). The
tax on alcohol prompted farmers in Western Pennsylvania to start a tax revolt,
now called the “Whiskey Rebellion,” as whiskey had come into use among poor
frontier traders as money in lieu of scarce gold and silver coin. Faced with
the rebellion, and several federal tax collectors being shot at by the rebels
(whom today would almost certainly be branded “terrorists”), President George
Washington put down the rebellion in a way that would have enraged today’s
neoconservatives who believe in a “unitary executive.” Washington first asked
permission of Congress to call up the state militia and enforce the internal
revenue laws. When congressional leaders agreed, Washington marched out at the
head of the Virginia and Pennsylvania militia and negotiated with the
“terrorists,” who agreed to put down their arms. And when two civilians were
shot accidentally by militiamen, Washington handed the soldiers over to local
prosecutors to be tried for murder charges. (Both were exonerated after an
investigation.) President Washington then pardoned most of the rebels.
Washington would today probably be branded by neocons as being a weak executive
who didn’t “support the troops.” Though unpopular in some parts of the country,
the tax on alcohol continued through the end of John Adams’ presidency.
A 1794 tax law also levied a tax on carriages that
tested the meaning of what was a “direct” tax and what was an “indirect” tax.
The law used the following language: “There shall be levied, collected, and
paid upon all carriages for the conveyance of persons, which shall be kept by
or for any person for his or her own use, or to be let out to hire or for the
conveyance of passengers, the several duties and rates following.” The language
prompted Massachusetts Federalist Fisher Ames to claim that “the duty falls not
on the possession, but on the use” and was therefore an indirect tax. But James
Madison — then a Virginia congressman — claimed that the tax was a direct tax
because it was not on the use but against everyone who “kept” a carriage,
regardless of whether it was used. And since the tax on carriages was not
apportioned among the states, Madison labeled the tax an “unconstitutional
tax.” Madison regarded a direct tax as one imposed directly on a person or
property, while an indirect tax was a tax imposed upon a transaction or
conditional event. The Supreme Court ultimately claimed the carriage tax was an
indirect tax in the 1796 case of Hylton
v. United States.
There has been some legitimate historical confusion
over the definition of direct taxes. When Rufus King of Massachusetts asked
during the 1787 constitutional convention “what was the precise meaning of
direct taxation,” James Madison recorded in his notes on the convention that
“No one answered.”
The Supreme Court seemed to rule on the propriety of
the carriage tax in the Hylton
case, rather than the constitutionality of it. “The truth is that the articles
taxed in one state should be taxed in another,” the court ruled. “A tax on
carriages, if apportioned, would be oppressive and pernicious. How would it
work? In some states there are many carriages and in others but few. Shall the
whole sum fall on one or two individuals in a state who may happen to own and
possess carriages? The thing would be absurd and inequitable. In answer to this
objection, it has been observed that the sum, and not the tax, is to be
apportioned, and that Congress may select in the different states different
articles or objects from whence to raise the apportioned sum. The idea is
novel. What, shall land be taxed in one state, slaves in another, carriages in
a third, and horses in a fourth, or shall several of these be thrown together
in order to levy and make the quoted sum? The scheme is fanciful. It would not
work well, and perhaps is utterly impracticable.”
In the Hylton
decision, the court ignored remarks made by John Marshall (who became U.S.
Supreme Court chief justice a few years later in 1801) during Virginia’s
ratification convention on the U.S. Constitution: “The objects of direct taxes
are well understood: they are but few: what are they? Lands, slaves, stock of
all kinds, and a few other articles of domestic property.” At the time of
Marshall’s remarks, Virginia had imposed a tax on carriages that was locally
considered a direct tax.
Today, Supreme Court justices have tried to define
direct taxes virtually out of existence in order to avoid the constitutional
requirement for apportionment of direct taxes. Justice Ruth Bader Ginsburg
argued in her concurrence in the Supreme Court’s ObamaCare decision, National Federation of Independent
Business v. Sebellius, “Even when the Direct Tax Clause was written
it was unclear what else, other than a capitation (also known as a “head tax”
or a “poll tax”), might be a direct tax.... The meaning of the Direct Tax
Clause is famously unclear.” The ObamaCare tax — imposed on citizens for doing
nothing, specifically “not” purchasing health insurance — would be classified
as a direct tax under a traditional understanding of the term, a fact
acknowledged by four of the nine members of the Supreme Court in the 2012
ObamaCare case.
By 1798, the United States was engaged in a quasi-war
with revolutionary France, and the Adams administration asked Congress to fund
a small navy to punish French naval piracy. Although U.S. privateers had
captured or sunk some 76 French ships, Congress complied, paying for it with
the nation’s first apportioned direct tax. The direct tax of 1798 imposed taxes
on “lands, houses and slaves” totaling $2 million over the next two years,
apportioned to states in amounts according to representation (as measured in
the U.S. census).
The young American nation quickly settled a peace with
France, its ally during the War for Independence, and the United States began
racking up huge budget surpluses by the end of the Adams presidency. In
response, Congress abolished all internal taxes. From 1802 through 1812, the
federal government subsisted on low tariffs as the only federal tax,
supplemented by sale of government lands and postal receipts (the latter being
operated informally as a revolving fund to pay for the postal service). By the
time of his second inaugural address in 1805, President Jefferson was able to
boast that “the suppression of unnecessary offices, of useless establishments
and expenses, enabled us to discontinue our internal taxes.... The remaining
revenue on the consumption of foreign articles, is paid cheerfully by those who
can afford to add foreign luxuries to domestic comforts, being collected on our
seaboards and frontiers only, and incorporated with the transactions of our
mercantile citizens, it may be the pleasure and pride of an American to ask,
what farmer, what mechanic, what laborer, ever sees a tax-gatherer of the
United States?”
Paying for the War of 1812
The advent of a second war against Britain in 1812
necessitated a resumption of internal taxes, especially as a British naval
blockade of American ports drastically reduced customs tariffs. Congress
enacted a variety of excise taxes and a direct tax of 1813 of $3 million
against land, houses, and slaves.
Following Massachusetts’ request during the
ratification process, Congress offered states a discount of up to 15 percent if
they collected the tax and paid it to the Treasury early. Seven of the 18
states elected to collect the tax themselves and forestall the pestilence of
federal tax collectors during the 1813 tax. As the war went poorly for America,
Congress enacted a second direct apportioned tax in 1815 for $6 million, also
upon land, houses, and slaves. Four states opted to collect the tax themselves while
the other 14 states did nothing, and the federal government appointed tax
commissioners in those 14 states to collect the tax. The U.S. government added
substantial debt during the war, but within a few years after the war,
President Monroe advocated a repeal of all internal taxes. Congress complied,
again funding the federal government exclusively through tariffs and the sale
of federal land. By Andrew Jackson’s presidency, the federal government had
paid off the entire national debt.
Paying for the Mexican-American War
Although Henry David Thoreau was reportedly jailed for
failing to pay a poll tax (a “head” tax) enacted to support the
Mexican-American War, Thoreau had actually refused to pay for a municipal tax,
not a federal tax, which had nothing to do with the war. The U.S. government
never had to raise internal taxes for the Mexican-American War, instead
choosing to pay for the war by quadrupling the national debt from $15.5 million
to $63 million between 1846 and 1849. In addition, the federal government
received increased tariff revenue from the Walker Tariff law passed in 1846,
the year before the war. The Walker Tariff was actually a tax cut on tariffs,
the “revenue-only” tariff drawn up by President Polk’s treasury secretary. It
increased international trade so dramatically that federal tax revenue
increased from $27 million in 1846 to $40 million in 1850. The massive increase
in tariff revenues — despite the lower rates — meant that the U.S. government
began running huge budget surpluses beginning in 1849, and paid off nearly all
of the national debt. By 1857, the national debt had been reduced to $23
million — less than one dollar per person in the country — and Congress passed
the Tariff of 1857, a huge tax cut that brought a few years of deficits but
economic prosperity in the lead-up to the Civil War.
Paying for the Civil War
The advent of the Civil War in 1861 brought more
direct taxes, at first also in the mold of the taxes from the War of 1812. The
1861 tax assessed $20 million, with the same plan, including a 15-percent
deduction for states who collected the tax themselves. All of the union states
except Delaware and the Colorado territory volunteered their assessment of the
1861 direct tax, but political support for an income tax and other taxes ended
the assessment of the apportioned direct tax. In addition, Congress imposed
excise taxes on many goods, including alcohol, tobacco, jewelry, and “legacies”
(inheritances).
By 1864, the new income tax was five percent on
incomes over $600 (equal to about $48,000 in current dollars) and up to 10
percent on incomes over $10,000 ($800,000 in current dollars). After the war,
the rates were reduced to a flat five-percent rate, and imposed only on incomes
over $1,000. After the war, clamor for repeal of the income tax increased
dramatically among citizens, business groups, and prominent newspapers and
politicians. In addition to the commissioner of the Internal Revenue Service,
the New York Times
opined on January 19, 1871, “We have reached the time when the income tax can
be no further defended. The people demand its repeal with one voice, and
repealed it should be.” Indeed, America’s first income tax was abolished the
next year.
The post-war Congresses were dominated by
protectionist Republicans who often kept tariffs so high that revenue suffered,
so they retained excise taxes on alcohol and tobacco to make up the revenue
difference. Most federal revenue was nevertheless raised by tariffs between
1866 and 1913. By 1892, Congress had paid off two-thirds of the $2.7 billion
Civil War debt that the U.S. government had assumed by 1866.
1894 Income Tax and More
Populist influence in a resurgent Democratic Party
prompted Congress to enact a tax on incomes over $4,000 at two percent, roughly
the equivalent of $320,000 today when measured against the gold standard of the
day. “The imposition of such a tax is but a gentle, playful exercise of a
dangerous power. It is merely showing demagogues the path of demagogy,” New
York Democratic Congressman William Bourke Cockran railed against the income
tax in congressional debate. “The men who offer this amendment as a sop to the
discontented will be swept away by the rising tide of socialism. They will
discover, when too late, that in overturning the barriers which separate
liberty from anarchy they have liberated ten thousand furies who will sweep
over them in a mad procession of anarchy and disorder.” Citing the nation’s
history under the Jefferson presidency, Cockran proclaimed support for
abolition of all the postbellum excise taxes.
But Cockran’s argument was in vain. Congress passed
the law anyway, and it was challenged in the Supreme Court as an
unconstitutional unapportioned tax. In the 1895 case of Pollock v. Farmers Loan and Trust
Company, the court ruled that a tax on rent or income from real
estate is a direct tax, because “the whole beneficial interest in the land
consisted in the right to take the rents and profits.” In addition, the court
ruled that taxes on stock and municipal bonds were direct as well. Ironically,
the Supreme Court in the Pollock
case did not rule that taxing income earned through labor was essentially a tax
on people, a capitation tax. Nonetheless, the court struck down the entire 1894
income tax in the Pollock
case, necessitating a constitutional amendment in order to enact a federal
income tax.
When the Spanish-American war started in 1898,
Congress enacted a variety of excise taxes as a means of paying for the cost of
the war, and Congress reduced debt to the $1.2 billion pre-war debt level by
1900. Interestingly, the telephone tax of three percent on long distance calls
— then affecting only the wealthiest families — was not abolished until 2006,
108 years after the war started.
As agitation for a new income tax increased in the
progressive era at the beginning of the 20th century, Congress enacted a
one-percent corporate income tax (on income over $5,000) in 1909. Congress also
passed the 16th Amendment out to the states for ratification that year. The
latter would open up a vast new revenue stream for government, in addition to a
means for the federal government to stick its nose into every family’s
business.
American history before Congress enacted the income
tax in 1913 (first imposed the following year) demonstrates that the federal
government was able to pay its bills, keep the nation largely out of debt, and
respect the privacy of American citizens. Even during wartime, Congress had a
method of imposing direct war taxes that respected states’ rights and American
citizens’ privacy.
The Congress did largely limit its legislating to
constitutionally enumerated powers of the federal government during that time
period. Only the multiplication of unconstitutional federal offices, along with
the demand by Congress to manipulate decisions of American consumers, has
necessitated imposition of the income tax. Or, conversely, the imposition of
the income tax made a massive increase of federal offices possible. Ironically,
despite the imposition of the income tax, Congress has more often engaged in
deficit spending and racked up a massive peacetime debt since enactment of the
16th Amendment.
This article is an example of the exclusive content
that's only available by subscribing to our print magazine. Twice a month get
in-depth features covering the political gamut: education, candidate profiles,
immigration, healthcare, foreign policy, guns, etc. Digital
as well as print options are available!
http://www.thenewamerican.com/culture/history/item/14268-before-the-income-tax
No comments:
Post a Comment